India’s carbon strategy to counter climate change
Low oil prices make it the right time to introduce a variable stabilizing carbon tax
The
environment ministry’s special secretary, Susheel Kumar, said earlier
this week that the Indian government is now looking to retrofit existing
national action plans on climate change while building new ones. With
the date of signing of the historic Paris climate change agreement in
April approaching fast, and its ratification to follow soon, that’s good
to hear. But the entire process will require care and
finesse—particularly the groundwork for integration with the world’s
networked carbon market.
This is a necessary condition for getting adequate circulation of
the new carbon currency founded in Paris—internationally transferred
mitigation outcomes. To de-jargonize: in a world carbon balance sheet
with a fixed net carbon credit, countries will be allowed to trade their
credits to other nations if they do not use up their Assigned Amount
Units due to lower emissions. This might be due to adjustment of
anthropogenic emissions at source or removal by sinks.
A third of the nations which announced
their intended nationally determined contributions (INDC) before the
Paris talks have already concurred on setting up of carbon markets. But
these are not the only possible model. While they consist of governments
determining the quantitative cap and markets determining price—allowing
domestic trade in carbon credits—the alternative of carbon taxation has
the government fixing the upstream price of fossil fuels, allowing
markets to determine the optimal quantity of use.
The latter Pigouvian tax (named after
English economist Arthur Pigou) to mould optimal social outcomes and
choices is the most suited option for the Indian scenario. The average
Indian’s carbon footprint is below the average per capita emission of
many other countries. And Indian techniques are still struggling to keep
pace with the decarbonizing rates of the developed world. Capping
carbon without alternatives can thus compromise development. The right
carbon tax levels, meanwhile, can internalize the social externality of
emissions and make it part of an individual’s choice set in a more
optimal manner.
But this also points to the core
problem. India—and developing countries in general—got the raw end of
the deal at Paris with an entirely disproportionate burden in the
context of historical emission trends and development needs. Not acting
is not an option either; various studies have shown that the long-term
costs of climate change in developing economies significantly outweigh
the short-term costs of climate change mitigation efforts. The trick,
then, is to find the correct balance that does not impose
disproportionately heavy costs in the near future.
The commodities crash has presented the government with that opportunity. The current tax levels—India has a de facto
carbon tax on its petroleum and oil products and a green tax on coal—do
not adequately consider the intensity of emissions in the country. The
prevailing low oil prices make it the right time to remedy this by
introducing a variable stabilizing carbon tax—one which rises when fuel
prices fall and falls when fuel prices rise. This can ensure that the
polluter will pay, keep emissions in check and incentivize the right
innovation and the right kind of energy—all without hitting the pace of
development too hard.
That said, this alone will not
suffice. Fuel is less price elastic and more income elastic in India.
This implies increasing carbon taxes alone will be insufficient to
reduce emissions as income levels rise. The price inelasticity is mainly
due to the absence of alternative energy sources and, in the past, fuel
subsidies. The International Solar Alliance and Make in India for
low-cost renewable technologies are good policy initiatives in the right
direction; they must be given greater impetus.
There are a host of complementary
measures to consider as well—from decarbonizing production of
electricity to research and development aimed at improving energy and
resource efficiency; from reducing waste to preserving and increasing
carbon sinks.
If New Delhi has to achieve its INDC
target—reduction by 33-35% of the 2005 levels by 2030—and hook itself
into the international carbon market, a long-term strategy with the
variable carbon tax at its core is a must.
Do you think India’s carbon taxation regime is sufficient to meet its INDC target?
No comments:
Post a Comment