The economics of the MGNREGS
Ten years after it was launched, the Mahatma Gandhi
National Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme (MGNREGS), which promises 100
days of employment to every rural household, is back in the news. More
people in rural India are seeking employment through the programme
across the country, with job numbers scaling a five-year peak.
Although
the MGNREGS seems to be reaching many more rural households than
before, urban opinion on the programme is sharply divided, both in the
mainstream and social media. Even the Narendra Modi government seems
divided on the programme, with the ministry of rural development
declaring that the 10th anniversary of the programme was a matter of “national pride” barely a year after Modi had derided the programme as a ditch-digging exercise on the floor of Parliament.
Academic
opinion on the MGNREGS, however, appears far more favourable than is
evident from the public discourse on the issue. A growing body of
research on the MGNREGS suggests that it has helped dent poverty,
reduced distress migration and raised the bargaining power of rural
labourers, especially among lower castes and women, the biggest
beneficiaries of the programme.
The latest UN
Development Programme report on human development hailed the programme
as a “milestone”, which had raised living standards of the poorest of
households by offering them a safety net. In a 2014 paper
analysing the impact of the programme, economists Stefan Klonner and
Christian Oldiges of the University of Heidelberg found that it had
reduced poverty by almost half during the agricultural lean season, by
helping smoothen seasonal spikes in the consumption of the poorest
families.
Using a different data set and a different methodology, a study by the National Council of Applied Economic Research (NCAER)
found that the MGNREGS “has reduced poverty overall by up to 32% and
has prevented 14 million people from falling into poverty”.
One
of the chief attractions of the scheme, according to economists, is the
self-selection mechanism of choosing beneficiaries. As Pranab Bardhan,
emeritus professor of economics at the University of California,
Berkeley, pointed out in an interview to Mint about a year ago, the MGNREGS is effectively a conditional cash-transfer programme.
The
condition is that the beneficiary has to work manually, which
immediately rules out the rich and the middle class. And in the absence
of credible data on poor households, this mechanism seems to be
effective in reaching those who need it the most. As the ministry’s
press release pointed out, the proportion of scheduled castes and tribes
(SCs and STs) among those the programme has reached is greater than
their share in the overall population of India.
The
MGNREGS has been instrumental in providing a safety net to the poor
because it “attracts mainly poor and vulnerable people such as
agricultural wage labourers, scheduled tribes, scheduled castes and
small, marginal farmers”, the NCAER report pointed out.
Given
that the key objective of the programme was to provide livelihood
security (especially during the agricultural lean season) and thereby
act as a safety net for the poor, it seems to have met that goal.
Nonetheless, the programme continues to face four main criticisms:
1.
It is not actually a demand-driven programme, and its success depends
on the willingness of the respective state governments and local bodies.
2. It has failed to create durable assets in rural areas.
3. It has contributed significantly to wage growth and stoked the fires of inflation.
4.
It has led to a massive leakage of public resources, and led to
unintended consequences in rural areas such as on educational outcomes.
The
first point is perhaps the most potent among the main criticisms of the
programme. Although it was launched as a demand-driven “workfare”
programme, in reality, the MGNREGS remains supply-driven with its reach
and impact determined by central, state and local government
functionaries, and varying widely across states.
Research
by Deepta Chopra of the Institute of Development Studies, Sussex, shows
that it is the government’s inability or rather unwillingness to award
jobs under the MGNREGS that has led to the decline of the programme in
Rajasthan.
In Rajasthan, the early success of
the programme turned out to be its biggest weakness, Chopra argues. She
points out that the involvement of grassroots organizations in the
implementation of the programme threatened local power brokers, who
resented the inability to award jobs according to their discretion.
This
led them to sabotage the process of demand-driven work schemes, and the
frontline workers charged with accepting applications for work refused
to accept them.
Economists Abhiroop Mukhopadhyay
of the Indian Statistical Institute, New Delhi, Himanshu of Jawaharlal
Nehru University and M.R. Sharan of Harvard University ound significant rationing of work by village headmen in Rajasthan. In many villages, people did not demand work because they were told that “they can request work only when it is available”.
Supply-side
issues in the MGNREGS are so important that a group of World Bank
economists found that even after mitigating the information asymmetry, participation may not increase.
Martin Ravallion and others of the World Bank ran a randomized
experiment in Bihar, where they showed a group of villagers an
informative video about the MGNREGS.
While the
perception of the programme certainly improved among those who viewed
the video, the impact on seeking and finding work through the programme
remain modest.
Given the supply-side nature of
the programme, better-functioning states such as those in south India
have made better use of the programme and received more funds compared
to poorer northern states such as Bihar and Uttar Pradesh, an analysis by former bureaucrat N.C. Saxena shows. Saxena suggests that pre-fixing state-wise MGNREGS allocations based on need would have been far more equitable.
While
creating durable assets was not the main objective of the programme, it
became a key aim in later years, and led to convergence with other
schemes. The evidence on this count is mixed, but the perception that it
has just been an empty ditch-digging exercise may be an urban myth.
While
there are anecdotal examples of poor assets created under the
programme, there is no systematic evidence suggesting that most or even a
majority of the assets are useless. A 2014 study
by a team led by economist Sudha Narayanan of the Indira Gandhi
Institute of Development Research (IGIDR) shows that most assets
recorded under the programme in Maharashtra exist in reality and not
just on paper.
Furthermore, an overwhelming
majority of rural households surveyed found the assets created under the
programme such as bunds, ponds, embankments, etc., to be useful for
them. Seventy-five per cent of the assets created are directly or
indirectly linked to agriculture, the study found.
Another
criticism that has been prevalent is that MGNREGS wages increase
agricultural wages and, hence, the cost of cultivation rises, which has
inflationary effects. In a 2012 paper,
Mehtabul Azam of Oklahoma State University analysed the impact of the
MGNREGS and found that the programme drove up wages of casual female
labour by 8%.
However, this is indicative of a
reduction in the gender-wage gap in India’s labour market more than of a
wage-inflation spiral. There is very little macroeconomic evidence to
suggest that the MGNREGS has been a key driver of inflation. A 2014 Reserve Bank of India report suggests that MGNREGS may not have had any significant impact on food inflation.
A new paper by Manisha Shah of UCLA and Bryce Steinberg of Brown University
argues that the MGNREGS has undesirable effects on educational
outcomes, particularly for adolescents. Using the Annual Status of
Education Report (ASER) survey data, the duo finds that children in
districts with more MGNREGS exposure perform worse in math, and are more
likely to drop out of school.
“We examine the
effect of MGNREGS, one of the largest workfare programmes in the world,
on human capital investment. Since MGNREGS increases labour demand, it
could increase the opportunity cost of schooling, lowering human capital
investment even as incomes increase. Using a household survey of test
scores and schooling outcomes for approximately 2.5 million rural
children in India, we show that each year of exposure to MGNREGS
decreases school enrolment by 2 percentage points and math scores by 2%
of a standard deviation amongst children aged 13-16. In addition, while
the impacts of MGNREGS on human capital are similar for boys and girls,
adolescent boys are primarily substituting into market work when they
leave school while adolescent girls are substituting into unpaid
domestic work.”
However, the negative effects of
older children dropping out of school could be compensated for by the
greater investment made on younger children in participating households.
In a forthcoming paper in the IZA Journal of Labour & Development,
economists Farzana Afridi, Abhiroop Mukhopadhyay and Soham Sahoo of the
Indian Statistical Institute show that a mother’s participation in the
MGNREGS not only raises the odds of the child attending school but is
also associated with better academic performance.
The
issue of corruption is not unique to the MGNREGS but afflicts most
state-run programmes, including those that provide for health or
infrastructure. As Bardhan pointed out, the leakages from the MGNREGS
are a small fraction of the subsidies to the better-off sections of
society, and it is, therefore, important not to lose a sense of
proportion in evaluating the programme.
A
fundamental issue that plagues all well-intentioned public programmes is
the lack of state capacity or political commitment to implement it
effectively. So far, the focus has been on building state capacity
through technocratic solutions (biometric payment systems, for
instance).
The evidence on automated payment
systems has been mixed. In Andhra Pradesh, a smart card-based payment
system has been found to have reduced the problems of delayed payments
and helped plug leakages.
Karthik Muralidharan
of the University of California, San Diego, who along with his
colleagues conducted the experiment on smart card payments for MGNREGS
wages in Andhra Pradesh found that
“despite the incomplete implementation, beneficiaries in carded mandals
experienced a faster, more reliable, and less corrupt payment
experience. The smart card system reduced the lag between working on an
MGNREGS project and collecting payment by 29%, and reduced the
unpredictability in the lag by 39%. Further, it reduced by 19% the time
workers spent collecting MGNREGS payments.”
While
the Andhra Pradesh experiment has been hailed as a success, news from
Chhattisgarh, another state that has done well in the implementation of
the MGNREGS, does not bode well for biometric payments. Supriya Sharma
of Scroll noted that the Aadhaar-based payment system is facing problems in Chhattisgarh, with many enrolment centres charging bribes while enrolling people.
In
summary, the MGNREGS program seems to have been reasonably successful
in meeting its goals. It may not have single-handedly transformed rural
India, but then it was never meant to do that. It was meant to be a
safety net for the poorest and most marginalized sections of society,
whose incomes went through sharp fluctuations across seasons.
Although
it suffers from implementation challenges and leakages, the MGNREGS has
reached the target population more effectively than most other
government schemes.
This is not to deny that the
programme needs reforms to perform better. While better use of
technology can solve certain problems, they are not adequate to fix
design bugs or issues of political accountability for the programme.
Given
the regional imbalances in fund allocation for the programme, it may be
worth considering allocating resources to states and districts that
require this programme the most, based on the levels of poverty and
exposure to drought, as Saxena argues.
It may
also be worthwhile to decentralize decision-making on the implementation
of the scheme once the allocation is based on a fair and transparent
criterion.
Rather than micromanage each aspect
of the programme, the central government should perhaps focus more on
monitoring key outcomes such as generation of employment and assets, and
on publicizing data relating to these aspects to make states and local
bodies accountable for the funds they receive.
No comments:
Post a Comment